Wednesday, September 7, 2011

How Wall Street Controls Oil

How Wall Street Controls Oil
And how OPEC will be the fall guy for $140 oil.

      Control over oil markets, once the province of the major integrated oil companies and then OPEC, may now be shifting into the hands of Wall Street’s ubiquitous investment banks. Oil industry experts noted this unwelcome transition at an early December 2006 OPEC-EU meeting in Vienna. Producers clearly were not happy to see their ability to influence prices undermined. EU representatives were equally unhappy because the changeover might increase price volatility. Wall Street types, meanwhile, denied responsibility.
      It has become clear in 2006 that one of Wall Street’s newest concepts—marketing commodities as an asset class—has altered world energy markets in a surprising fashion. In particular, the injection of cash into commodities by passive investors such as pension funds has created a rich financial incentive to accumulate inventories. Participants in physical energy markets (both oil and natural gas) have responded by putting away almost record amounts and building new storage facilities. The stocks amassed, in turn, have undermined the ability of oil exporters to control prices. OPEC ministers recognize that under certain circumstances the accruing stocks could precipitate a sudden, temporary drop in crude prices similar to the one observed in natural gas last spring.




          At the same time, the stock and price rise threatens to raise political hackles. Legislators will no doubt
respond this spring with a spate of hearings and perhaps laws directed at an industry incorrectly accused
of  hoarding.
           Here I describe the latest development in the energy market twists and turns of the last three
decades.  Its appearance has made the tools traditionally used to predict oil market fluctuations at least  
temporarily obsolete.
                                                                  A SURPRISING CHANGE

Those who watch oil markets closely were startled last June as oil prices and inventories simultaneously rose to unprecedented highs. The price rise itself was not a surprise. Nor was the stock climb to levels not observed since the 1998 shock. However, the two events occurring simultaneously caught the attention of many and for good reason: historically, high prices have been associated with low inventories and vice versa.
          The surprising parallel increase in stocks and oil prices can be observed in Figure 1. There I compare
U.S. commercial crude stock levels from January 1986 through December 2006 with the spot price of WTI
[West Texas Intermediate, an oil pricing benchmark], which trades on the New York Mercantile Exchange.
For presentation purposes, stocks are graphed against the left vertical axis and prices against the right.

Control over oil markets may now be shifting into the hands of Wall Street’s
ubiquitous investment banks.

One the left vertical axis and prices against the right. One can note an unusual surge in stocks beginning in
January 2005 that matches the crude price rise from $45 to $74 per barrel.
      The concurrent upsurge in prices and stocks was unusual by historical standards. In the past, inventories
of oil and other commodities moved counter cyclically with prices. Commercial users of commodities have
always been notoriously parsimonious. Indeed, few managers will risk tying up working capital to accum
mulate additional stocks, and oil companies have previously been very aggressive in minimizing inventories.

Crude for delivery in 2010 will pass $140 per barrel.

Moreover, no publicly traded company has reported holding speculative stocks.
      On this occasion, however, the stock boost was driven by a profit motive rather than a speculative one.
Commercial firms were given the chance to gain by keeping stocks, and they responded by increasing their
holdings.
      Wall Street provided the opportunity to benefit from adding stocks. For the last fifteen years, investment bankers have touted commodities as an asset class.
In the last two years, the idea gained recognition. Commodities were sold as an alternative to traditional bond and stock investments. Building on academic research at Yale and Wharton, analysts from Goldman Sachs, Deutsche Bank, Barclays, PIMCO, and other institutions have circulated papers that demonstrate how investors achieve useful diversification by allocating a small portion of their portfolios to ommodities. The diversification occurs because returns from commodities are negatively correlated with returns on equities or bonds.

Oil Storage Problem

      Oil can no longer be held in open pits as it was in the 1930s. It must be kept in tanks or on
ships, and both have a fixed supply. As storage fills, the prices facility owners charge for it increase. The boost in storage costs drives down cash prices. Such an impact occurred in summer 2006 when cash prices in U.S. natural gas markets dropped by more than 60 percent to $4.50 per million Btu. In an even more extreme case, in September natural gas sellers briefly paid buyers in Great Britain to take gas. (The statement is correct. British firms paid buyers to take gas because storage was full.) Thus Wall Street’s commodity asset class innovation has the potential to destabilize energy markets thoroughly.

Control over oil markets may now beshifting into the hands of Wall Street’s
ubiquitous investment banks.

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------



      Many pension fund managers have been convinced. Between 2004 and 2006, as much as $100 billion may have been invested in commodities. Figure 2, taken from a Goldman Sachs presentation, shows a rough estimate of the cash input from passive investors. One can see from the graph that financial          institutions had marketed the idea as early as 1991. However, one can also note the idea only took hold in 2004.
      Those investing in commodities are not typical of other commodity market participants. They are not speculators. They do not trade frequently, and they do not sell short. Investors buy a diversified portfolio of commodities and hold on to it. Energy commodities, particularly oil, make up a large portion of the indexes because energy accounts for a large share of the economy.
      Proponents of commodity investing recommend full collateralization of contracts. Although commodity futures are by definition margined transactions, commodity investors set aside the contract’s full value when they buy. Thus the purchaser of 1,000 barrels of crude will reserve $60,000 if oil sells at $60 per barrel. The money not used for margin is invested in a highly liquid instrument such as a Treasury bill.
      The most widely quoted academic proponents of commodity investment (Gary Gorton and Geert Rouwenhorst) do not promise investors returns from price appreciation. Rather they demonstrate how a return can be earned as a result of markets normally being in “backwardation,” a condition that occurs when cash prices exceed futures prices. As they explain,
           Keynes and Hicks postulated the theory of normal backwardation, which states
that the risk premium will, on average, accrue to the buyers. They envisioned a world in which
producers of commodities seek to hedge the price risk of their output. For example, a producer
of grain sells grain futures to lock in the future price of the crops and obtain insurance
against the price risk of grain at harvest time.
          Speculators provide this insurance and buy futures, but they demand a futures price that is
below the spot price expected to prevail at the maturity of the futures contract. By “backward
dating” the futures price relative to the expected future spot price, speculators receive a risk
premium from producers for assuming the risk of future price fluctuations.



      For illustration, I show in Figure 3 the forward price curve of oil on January 1, 2003. At that time, the first future settled for $31.68 per barrel and the second future at $30.50. If spot prices remained at $31.68 per barrel, the investor could count on making $1.18 per barrel in 30 days. Investors could earn an annual return of almost 60 percent if they repeated the exercise each month by “rolling” their investment into the next contract.
          Gorton and Rouwenhorst examine data for a thirty-year period and show that a portfolio of commodities structured as described above would earn returns that match those from bonds and equities. They also show the returns are negatively correlated, implying that commodity investments help diversify
portfolios.

INTRODUCING “NORMAL CONTANGO”
The movement of passive investors into commodities shifted markets from backwardation to contango, the condition that occurs when futures prices exceed cash prices. Quite simply, energy markets today are too
small to accommodate the increased activity of investors seeking to buy commodities and still stay in backwardation. Producers who might sell futures to hedge the risk of a price decline generally do not do so, having been counseled by other representatives of the same investment banks that buyers of their equities did not want them to hedge. The consequence of this impasse was predictable. Futures prices rose relative to cash prices. As can be seen from Figure 4, the market shifted from backwardation on January 1, 2003, to contango by July 2006. (In Figure 4, the 2003 curve is graphed against the left vertical axis and the 2006
curve against the right because the price level in 2006 is roughly double that of 2003.) The change in the curve’s shape is remarkable.
Usually, markets become more backwardated as cash prices rise.
Inventory accumulation began once markets shifted into contango because it became profitable for commercial firms to add to stocks. In a contango market, a company acquiring stocks avoids the risk of a
price decline by hedging. Thus in July an oil company could acquire incremental oil for $76 per barrel and simultaneously hedge the volume by selling futures for $80 per barrel. This transaction— referred to historically as a “cash and carry”—nets the company a $4-per-barrel profit whether oil rises to $100 or
falls to $10. Not surprisingly, firms jumped at the opportunity. As noted above, both prices and inventories rose.
In theory, companies could acquire oil indefinitely.  Prices could rise and stocks follow. However, at least one real impediment to this scenario exists: storage. Oil can no longer be held in open pits as it was in the



1930s. It must be kept in tanks or on ships, and both have a fixed supply.
As storage fills, the prices facility owners charge for it increase. The boost in storage costs drives down cash prices. Such an impact occurred in summer 2006 when cash prices in U.S. natural gas markets dropped by more than 60 percent to $4.50 per million Btu. In an even more extreme case, in September natural gas sellers briefly paid buyers in Great Britain to take gas. (The statement is correct. British firms paid buyers to take gas because storage was full.) Thus Wall Street’s commodity asset class innovation has the potential to destabilize energy markets thoroughly.

POLICY DILEMMAS
The emergence of high inventories and high prices and the possibility of a price collapse create dilemmas for OPEC and policymakers in consuming countries. For OPEC, the risk is obvious. Lawmakers in consuming nations seeking to reduce greenhouse gas emissions are also troubled by the prospect of low prices. Yet, there may be little they can do to ameliorate the situation.
OPEC’s problem concerns the price level. OPEC can and has cut oil production to squeeze stocks and raise
prices. In March 1999, Saudi Arabia led the organization in a program to reduce consumer inventories across the globe. Between mid-1998 and early 2001, global stocks shrunk by almost 700 million barrels. When they implemented this policy, OPEC officials predicted that prices would rise as stocks declined. Many doubted this, but by early 2001 prices had tripled from $10 to $30 per barrel.
In early December 2006, Saudi Arabia’s oil minister Ali Al-Naimi commented that global inventories were rising again. He fretted that prices might come under pressure.
Other OPEC members stated more explicitly that production cuts were needed to reduce world stocks by 100 million barrels. There is a problem with this thinking, however. OPEC cannot make inventories decline by cutting output. A reduced oil supply might induce those holding stocks to sell and take profits. Alternatively, they might decide not to sell, in which case consumption would have to decrease. In this second scenario, crude oil prices would need to increase between 10 and 20 percent to balance the market. This would bring crude back to the summer peaks of nearly $80 per barrel. Of course, a crude price hike is just what those marketing commodities as assets seek. More investors and more money would pour into commodity indexes, much of it into oil. The incentive to hold stocks would strengthen and inventories might build despite OPEC’s production cut.
The process will end when storage fills. Then OPEC will need to reduce output further or risk prices falling
precipitously. We could very well observe a price decline and OPEC attempts to arrest it. During 2007, I suspect we will see an oil price surge followed by a rush of cash into commodities. Forward prices will be bid higher.
Crude for delivery in 2010 will pass $140 per barrel. Stocks will rise further while Congress and the press accuse oil companies of hoarding. Then buyers will realize at some point that they have no place to put the oil and prices will tumble. The history of commodity market cycles suggests the decline could be spectacular. Single digit prices are possible, although probably only for a day or two.
As an EU official said privately, “The market has been destabilized.”


Quite simply, energy markets today are too small to accommodate the
increased activity of investors seeking to buy commodities and still stay in
backwardation.
In an even more extreme case, in September natural gas sellers briefly
paid buyers in Great Britain to take gas.

2 comments:

  1. Islam and the Global Oil Economy





    “They hate our freedom” President George Bush in an address to a joint meeting of congress and the American people September 2001.
    Radical Islamic movements are often portrayed to be fundamentally at odds with western conceptions of freedom.
    The terrorist attacks on the World Trade Center are seen to be an expression of radical Islam’s hatred of western economic freedom and capitalism more generally.


    McWorld vs. Jihad

    McWorld: The globalizing powers of capitalism.
    Jihad: In this instance, the “narrowly conceived faiths” opposed to the homogenizing force of capital.
    This play on words seems to suggest that the Islamic faith is in some way fundamentally anti-capitalist and anti-modern.


    Is there one Islam?

    Like Christianity, the Islamic faith can take on a variety of different forms and traditions
    Sufism and Wahhabism
    Differences revolve around interpretations of the Prophet’s thoughts and beliefs, interpretations of Sharia law, and interpretations of who should be the Prophet’s successor.


    Islam and Capitalism

    Given the diversity of Islamic traditions, it is impossible to assume that there is something fundamentally anti-capitalist about Islam.
    It may be better to think of Islam as a diverse set of traditions that revolve around the Koran and the teachings of the Prophet, rather than as a homogenous, coherent entity.




    Radical Islam and the Oil Economy

    Mitchell argues that instead of thinking in simple binaries, such as McWorld vs. Jihad, we should think of the rise of radical Islam as a process of McJihad.
    By this he means that in two of the most powerful global industries, arms and oil, the mechanisms of profit making appear to depend in large part on the social force and moral authority of conservative Islamic movements.
    In other words, the mechanisms of global capitalism depend in important ways on the existence of radical, authoritarian Islamic regimes.


    The political economy of oil

    Oil is a strategic commodity with a low elasticity of demand. This allows for enormous profits to be made.
    Oil is the second most abundant liquid in the world. Therefore to make profits oil companies and oil producing countries need to actively create scarcity.
    One country, Saudi Arabia, has the greatest surplus of oil in the world.
    Its unused oil capacity, which can be easily turned off and on, is greater than the total oil production of every country except Russia and the US. Around 3 million barrels a day of surplus capacity.
    The possibility of earning oil profits anywhere in the world depends on the political control of Saudi Arabia.


    Political control of Saudi Arabia

    The monarchical rule of Saudi Arabia is achieved through an unstable relationship between multinational oil companies and radical Islamic movements.
    The global political economy of oil depends in large measure on the existence of radical Islamic movements.
    Loss of control over Saudi oil would threaten the possibility of extracting massive profits from the sale of oil.


    Wahhabism and the formation of Saudi Arabia

    Wahhabism, otherwise know as followers of the doctrine of Tawhid, or muwahhidun.
    Ikhwan, or Brotherhood, are followers of this Islamic tradition.
    Their goals were:
    1. To replace the polytheistic traditions of Arab nomads and “heretical Muslims” with the strict monotheism of tawhid
    2. To create an egalitarian Muslim society opposed to colonial relations with the west.




    Initially with British, and later with American military support, Ibn Saud, the first king and founder of Saudi Arabia, was able to mobilize the religious zeal of the Ikhwan to expand his control over the Arabian peninsula following World War I.
    As new parts of Arabia fell under his control he gained favor with the Ikhwan by allowing them to pursue one of their primary goals: to punish people they thought to be heretics (including Shia muslims) or people who acted ‘immorally’.

    ReplyDelete
  2. The rise of the house of Saud

    After taking control of the Arabian peninsula Ibn Saud renamed the region Saudi Arabia, the only country in the world to be named after a single family.
    Ibn Saud used oil rents derived from Aramco (The Arab American Oil Company) to finance the consolidation of his power in the region.
    Ikhwan leadership were willing to ignore the presence of a foreign oil company in exchange for weapons and support for their program to convert Arabia to the teachings and discipline of tawhid.


    The Mujahideen

    By the 1950’s the Ikhwan militias became incorporated into the formal mechanisms of rule in Saudi Arabia, renamed the National Guard, their members are known as mujahideen (those who fight jihad).
    In the 1980s the madrasas (religious schools) run by the Ikhwan became sources of political discontent in Saudi Arabia over rising poverty among the middle class and the perceived colonial relationship between the Saudi elite and the US government.
    To quell this dissent the House of Saud exported as many as 12,000 majahideen to Afghanistan to fight a jihad against the Soviets. This was in part coordinated by a young mujahideen named Osama bin Laden.


    Al-Qaeda and Afghanistan

    Cold war politics in the US: funded the mujahideen and drew out the conflict in order to draw the USSR into a Vietnam like quagmire in Afghanistan
    From the mujahideen emerged Al-Qaeda.
    The mujahideen’s success against the Soviet’s emboldened their movement.


    Conclusion

    In order to maintain the global scarcity, and therefore massive profits, of oil, multinational oil companies financed the arming and training of radical Islamic movements.
    This was done in order to gain political control over the massive oil fields of Saudi Arabia.
    Thus, the rise of radical Islamic movements in the Middle East have their roots in efforts to control the production of Saudi oil through the moral control of radical Islam.

    ReplyDelete